This article is sourced from today's (Friday the 22nd of February) Business Inspector, and was written by Philip Soos.
"For those interested in the Australian residential property
market, below are a collection of figures illustrating long-term trends.
Housing prices and land values are compared to a basket of fundamental metrics.
Australians are fortunate because much data on real estate and financial
markets are publically available, going into depth not seen in other countries.
Comparing housing prices to inflation is one of the
more common indicators in property market analysis. If the trend is fairly even
over time, then there is no indication that people are favouring housing
relative to other goods and services. On the other hand, if there is a wide
divergence between housing prices and inflation, this tells us that people are
considering housing to be relatively more important. Interestingly, every rise
in real prices has led to a downturn, with the one exception of 1961-1964.
Another popular method of determining property valuation is comparing housing
prices to rents. In a fairly efficient market, the costs of buying and renting
should closely match each other, though due to factors such as taxes, risks,
and interest rates, it is unlikely that costs will equal. Since the post-WWII
boom, the ratio has unevenly decreased. Upswings in the ratio suggest the
presence of a bubble: the mid-1970s, early 80s, late 80s, and today.
As with inflation and rents, housing prices have also outstripped incomes as
well. Unfortunately, the Australian Bureau of Statistics does not provide a
long-term median household disposable income series, so the denominator is
derived by dividing aggregate real gross household income by the number of
occupied households on an annual basis. This results in an unusually high HDI
as averages are typically greater than medians, and is further amplified as the
HDI is stacked with artefacts like superannuation which cannot be drawn upon to
finance debt repayments. While the outcome is a rather low ratio, it keeps in
line with that developed in Stapledon’s 2012 housing paper and shows a
substantial increase from 1996 onwards. A more realistic median measure would result
in a higher ratio, and the latest Demographia report shows it to be so.
It is easy to see the major cause of the Great Depression: a deflating land
bubble, centred in the commercial property market. Every major rise in the
ratio has resulted in a downturn, correlating with, and arguably, causing the
economic recessions of the mid-70s, early 80s, and early 90s. The ratio has
doubled from the trough in 1996 through to the peak in 2010. The substantial
rise in the ratio during the late 1970s was likely due to an anomaly in
splicing multiple land value series together, though part of the rise is
justifiable because of a residential bubble.
The same story emerges when land values are compared with GDP per capita, which
is arguably a better fundamental metric than GDP itself. As with the previous
figure, the ratio has doubled during the same time period.
The Kavanagh-Putland Index measures the ratio of property sales to GDP. This
metric is considered useful because in times of speculative fervour, investors
flip properties to one another, increasing the total value of sales on an
annual basis. When real estate markets tank, sales inevitably fall as potential
buyers stand by the wayside waiting for further price falls. The ratio peaked
in 2004 after housing prices jumped in the years previous.
The value of housing stock to GDP has likewise moved in the same direction as
house prices to inflation and land values to GDP. It is the land component
rather than the dwellings that has increased in value over GDP.
The primary determinant of the boom-bust cycle in the land market is
availability of credit/debt used to speculate on rising capital values of real
estate. While data on private debt goes back to 1861, aggregate land values
only begin in 1910. Debt peaked in 1893, driving a colossal commercial land
bubble that burst, causing the worst depression in Australia’s recorded
history. Again the same occurred during the 1920s, with the same result. It
took until the 1970s for the debt cycle to assert itself once again, with one
boom and bust after another. Debt reached the highest peak on record in 2008,
driving the largest land boom on record.
Unsurprisingly, the cause for the massive rise in housing prices and land
values, along with net rental income losses, is the colossal increase in
household debt, primarily composed of mortgage debt. It has more than
quadrupled since 1988, rapidly accelerating during the 1990s and 2000s. The
ratio peaked in 2010 as did housing prices, which is clearly no coincidence.
As household debt has climbed, so too has debt as a percentage of household
assets. The ratio will rise as housing prices continue to soften. It has
tripled from 1990 through to 2008 before the GFC, falling and then resuming its
upward climb.
The same has occurred with housing debt to disposable income, tripling over the
same time period.
Despite very high interest rates during the early 1990s, the ratio peaked in
2008 due to the staggering debt load of households, even at lower interest
rates. It is no surprise that this ratio closely matches the net income losses
experienced by property investors as shown in the next figure.
Perhaps the most telling of all data are investors’ ability to finance the debt
and routine expenses on their residential properties. In the midst of the late
1980s commercial land bubble, an element of residential speculation caused real
housing prices to increase, most notably in Sydney and Perth. Speculators
suffered income losses from 1988/89 to 1991/92 while seeking capital gains. The
market later stabilised before making the largest net income losses from 2000
onwards, signifying a zero net yield and massive residential bubble.
The obvious cause of these losses is due to the rise in interest repayments
rather than running expenses, which have remained stable at around 50 per cent
of gross rental income. Interest repayments peaked in 2008, driven by higher
interest rates before the GFC hit.
Not only are investment properties overvalued, the entire residential stock is.
The vast majority of properties are owner-occupied, at almost 70 per cent.
Since 2004, all owners on aggregate have been running net income losses which
do not bode well for them once capital values stop increasing.
Once again, it is interest repayments that are the cause of the income losses.
A slight uptick in expenses during the 2000s surely didn’t help, but has since
then fallen back to its long-run average.
Despite the best efforts of the National Housing Supply Council and the FIRE
sector (finance, insurance and real estate) to spruik a housing shortage, the
long-term trends show dwelling growth has consistently outpaced population
growth since WWII. From 2008 to 2009, the trend reversed temporarily.
Perhaps the only positive factor is the government’s relatively low position of
gross debt to GDP. The fashionable idea often repeated these days is that
rising public debt poses a risk to the economy has little substance in reality.
Compared to the pre-WWII era, the governments of today are a picture of fiscal
responsibility and prudence, with the rise in taxation revenue helping to
offset the need for using debt. In the event of a substantial and prolonged
downturn in the economy, the federal and state governments are well-placed to
debt-spend.
A better measure of government debt is net rather than gross debt, and even
better is the net rather than gross interest repayment burden, expressed as a
percentage of GDP. What matters for countries that have high levels of
government debt is how great the net interest repayment burden is. This is what
separates the US and Japan – countries with a relatively high level of
government debt – with the basket-case PIIGS nations (Portugal, Italy, Ireland,
Greece and Spain). Australia is currently situated in an excellent position,
and even if the government debt to GDP ratio were to rise, this does not
necessarily translate into higher net interest repayments if the Reserve Bank
further cut interest rates from already historical lows and purchased
government bonds.
Increases in the government debt to GDP ratio are typically due to two
occurrences: world wars (1914 to 1918 and 1939 to 1945) and responses to
economic downturns caused by private debt-financed speculation: the 1890s,
1930s, mid-1970s, early 1980s, early 1990s and the GFC in 2008. The rise in the
ratio before the 1890s was due to colonial government mass construction of
public infrastructure. It is obvious to see which type of debt today presents
an overwhelming macro risk to the economy. Government debt will inevitably rise
to counter private debt-deleveraging but it is very unlikely that political
parties will engage in the necessary and timely expansion needed to ward off
the adverse effects of debt-deflation.
In conclusion, the data presented should provide more than enough evidence to
suggest that Australia’s residential property market (specifically land market)
is vastly overvalued, driven by debt-financed speculation and the relative
non-taxation of land rent. While land bubbles have been a continual feature of
the Australian economy, what separates this cycle is the relative enormity of
the boom in both land values and private debt. A smaller private debt to GDP
ratio during the 1880s and 1920s was enough to produce two devastating
depressions, including a number of recessions during the mid-1970s, early 1980s
and early 1990s.
The question is often asked why housing prices are so high. Instead, the real
question is to ask why prices are so low. The banking and financial system is
ready to lend absurd amounts of debt to the willing army of 'greater fools',
and has constructed an elaborate chain from mortgage brokers’ offices through
to the business development managers at the banks in order to commit extensive
fraud by manipulating loan application forms. This is the 'six degrees of
separation' Denise Brailey has uncovered. Consequently, the only determinant
that prevents the banks from lending more credit is debtors’ ability to finance
repayments out of current income. Only when it becomes difficult to finance
repayments will the housing and land markets finally capitulate.
It is often claimed “this time is different". It certainly is, but not for
the reasons usually given: Australia has not experienced a land bubble of this
magnitude in its history. Seven in ten adults own property, solvency of the
FIRE sector is dependent upon ever-increasing capital values and the
governments’ addiction to housing-related tax revenue and votes, its
none-too-surprising bubble deniers have been out in full force, asserting
housing prices are based upon fundamental valuations. Also unsurprising is that
all bubble deniers have conflicts of interest, and in an age of the secular
equivalent of religious fanaticism and greed, facts and history are
conveniently dispensed down the memory hole.
The only option left to policymakers is to continually kick the can down the
road, hoping the bust does not occur on their watch. The result, as seen with
the Rudd government’s additional First Home Owner’s Boost, was precisely that.
This intervention restarted the debt machine, re-inflating housing and land
prices to a new, higher peak in 2010. The overarching private debt bubble,
which began in 1964, will likely come to an end once and for all when the
government runs out of fuel to throw on the fire.
Philip Soos is a researcher at Deakin University's School of
International and Political Studies."